Premium
This is an archive article published on June 22, 2006

Big is beautiful

Jet-Sahara negotiations show we must shed our fear of large corporate players

.

There’s a core policy issue flagged by the Jet-Sahara deal and by similar corporate negotiations. The issue is at the heart of liberalisation. Liberalisation and reforms are about market-based decisions and competition. Competition is good for consumers and bad for inefficient producers, of both goods and services. To what extent should the government interfere in the functioning of the market? Does competition need government handholding?

Most people have a notion of perfect competition with hundreds of producers floating around, all selling undifferentiated products (or services). That notion of perfect competition only exists in textbooks of economic theory. Even in the agricultural sector, what with branding and product differentiation, perfect competition is fast disappearing. Twenty years ago, how many people thought salt or atta would be branded? The world is fast moving towards two or three in every segment (cold drinks, aircraft manufacturers, operating systems, browsers, currencies, any particular newspaper or magazine segment), with additional ones thrown in as no more than flavour. Yet, in sector after sector, we have this fascination for the small and an abhorrence of the large, support for David rather than Goliath. 33 years ago, E.F. Schumacher wrote a book titled Small is Beautiful and it was a rage.

Fashions come and go, but beauty has nothing to do with business. Large means exploitation of economies of scale and scope and that reduces costs of production. If those lower costs are passed on to consumers, what is wrong with being large? Large makes it easier to enforce regulatory standards, even bring consumer pressure. If thousands of buses, taxis, trucks and auto-rickshaws in Delhi are instead run by three or four large fleet operators, what will be terribly wrong? As a counterpoint to that notion of perfect competition, we have yet another figment of the imagination, a single producer or monopoly. The world of monopolies is also fast disappearing, thanks to changes in technology and possibilities of unbundling. Rarely, not even in the broad infrastructure sector, will one find examples of what used to be called natural monopolies, situations where technical reasons warrant a single producer. For everything in the world, there are now substitutes, except in instances of unnatural monopolies. Unnatural monopolies are situations where government licensing restrictions lead to monopolies. It seems very difficult to give up the legacies of the Hazari Committee (1955), the Mahalanobis Committee (1964) and the Dutt Committee (1965), all contributing to the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices (MRTP) Act (1969).

Story continues below this ad

Industrial licensing led to monopolies, of the unnatural kind, and other problems. But instead of treating the disease of licensing, we decided to clamp down on concentration of power. This distrust of the large is reinforced by another mindset, that somehow public sector monopolies are preferable to private ones. A large Indian/Air India market share is fine, but a Jet/Sahara one less so. This is doubtful logic. Apart from anything else, a public sector monopoly tends to be completely open-ended. Exit is impossible. There will be subsidies from the budget in case of losses. Faced with competition, consolidation and shakeouts in any sector are inevitable, including aviation and telecom. If Indian/Air India are not autonomous enough to function according to commercial principles and handle the competition, that is a completely separate problem. Nor should the interests of smaller operators become a national interest issue. This is not to suggest that competition descends like manna from heaven. Had that been the case, competition policy instruments wouldn’t have been necessary. Nor would we have needed the Competition Commission of India (CCI). Developed countries also have competition policy instruments. The debate should be about what form these instruments take; security is a different matter altogether.

Unfortunately, we always react to market shares, the structure aspect of competition policy. Jet/Sahara, if it works out, will have a market share of more than 50 per cent, perhaps 60 per cent on the Delhi-Mumbai sector during peak hours, perhaps even more for parking bays in Mumbai and Delhi. However, such dominance is a static concept and fresh entry and other changes should break down market shares unless there are barriers in the way of fresh entry, including those created by the government.

The point thus is not dominance per se, but what use is being made of the dominance, something CCI also stresses. Except for mergers and acquisitions, no sensible competition policy instruments therefore focus on market shares alone. With mergers and acquisitions, there is a special problem, because there can be significant transaction costs in breaking up a combined entity once a merger or acquisition has taken place. In similar vein, we shouldn’t be bothered about performance aspects of competition policy either, meaning high prices or profitability. Again, unless there are entry barriers, these will be broken down and are not sustainable. It is certainly fashionable to talk about predatory pricing. Predatory pricing is a situation where one artificially lowers prices to drive out the competition, and once competition is ousted, raises prices thereafter.

But in practice, predatory pricing is impossible to test a priori. One only knows this post facto, when the damage has been done. Incidentally, if one takes predatory pricing seriously (most newspaper pricing practices, for example, should be prohibited). There is an apocryphal joke about competition policy based on pricing and concerns three CEOs who were in hell. The first charged a lower price than the competitor and was there because of predatory pricing. The second charged a higher price and was there because of monopolistic pricing. The third charged the same price and was there because of collusion.

Story continues below this ad

What we should instead do is to recognise the transition from licensing to regulation and focus on conduct-type competition policy, that is, unfair and restrictive business practices. The former concerns relations between a firm and consumers, while the latter concerns relations between a firm and its rivals. The former is the province of the Consumer Protection Act, the latter of CCI or similar regulators. However, mindsets are difficult to change and therein lies the problem. Many people are still in love with the MRTP Act and the MRTP Commission.

The writer is secretary-general, PHDCCI

Latest Comment
Post Comment
Read Comments
Advertisement
Advertisement
Advertisement
Advertisement